1

Objectives for Chapter 23: Monetarism – Part II

At the end of Chapter 23, you will be able to answer the following:

1. What is thePhillips Curve?

2. How did the Phillips Curve shift in the 1970s? How did it shift in the

1980s?

3. How does the Phillips Curve relate to the Aggregate Supply curve?

4. Describe thejob search model.

5. What is meant by “adaptive expectations”? by “rational expectations”?

6. What is the“natural rate of unemployment”?

7. What is the “short-run”?

8. Use the theory of job searching in a period of unanticipated inflation to explain the short-runPhillips Curve as well as the shifts that occurred in the 1970s and 1980s.

9. Then, use the same theory to explain what will result in the long-run.

10. Explain what would occur if the government or Federal Reserve tried to keep the unemployment ratepermanently below the natural rate.

11 What is the long-run Phillips Curve? How is it different from the short-run Phillips

Curve? What is the long-run Aggregate Supply Curve?

12. Why is the long-run Phillips Curvevertical? Why is the long-run aggregate supply curve vertical?

13. Explain why an attempt to keep unemployment below the natural rate will cause accelerating inflation (this is called the acceleration hypothesis).

14. According to the acceleration hypothesis, a recession is needed to lower inflation.

Explain why.

15. Explain what will result if actual unemployment is above the natural rate and the

government or the Federal Reserve stimulates aggregate demand.

Chapter 23: The Basic Theory of Monetarism (Part II) (latest revision

June 2006) (This Chapter is rather technical and may take two class periods to complete.)

1. The Phillips Curve

To understand the last thirty years, we need to begin with the Phillips Curve. The curve is named for the statistician who first developed it in the late 1950s, an Australian working in Great Britain. On the horizontal axis is plotted the unemployment rate. On the vertical axis is plotted the inflation rate. (Actually, Phillips plotted the percentage change in wages, not prices. But the two changes are related. And the most important conclusions of the Phillips Curve follow if we use prices instead of wages.) When the data are plotted and a line illustrating the trend is drawn the Phillips Curve looks as follows:

Inflation Rate

D

R

0 Unemployment Rate

What does the Phillips Curve tell us? It says that there is a trade-off between unemployment and inflation. When the inflation rate is falling, the unemployment rate is rising. And when the unemployment rate is falling, the inflation rate is rising. Policies that improve one of the issues will worsen the other issue.

What Phillips also discovered was that this trade-off had been stable. His data extended back nearly 100 years. Whatever the relation had been in the 1950s, the same relation had existed in the 1920s, the 1890s, and even the 1870s. This was an amazing discovery. Relationships in Economics rarely stay the same for even a few years. But Phillips had discovered a relation that seemed to have been the same for nearly 100 years. Phillips had used data for Great Britain. Data were then collected in more than 30 different countries. All studies, including ones done for the United States, found a stable trade-off between inflation rates and unemployment rates.

In the 1960s, people were very excited about this discovery. If the relation between inflation and unemployment were indeed stable, people could treat it as analogous to a menu. Just as one can have very good food but have to pay a high price, one can have very low rates of unemployment but have to pay the “price” of high rates of inflation. And just as one can have a low cost meal but pay the “price” of very poor food, one can have low rates of inflation but pay the “price” of high rates of unemployment. Or perhaps one might choose the middle --- moderate rates of inflation and unemployment. In any case, there was a political choice to be made. At the risk of some exaggeration, one can say that Democrats would be more likely to make choices like D. These had lower rates of unemployment and somewhat higher rates of inflation. And Republicans would be more likely to make choices like R. These had lower rates of inflation and somewhat higher rates of unemployment. However, there were limits; neither political party could let unemployment rates or inflation rates become too high.

Having discovered a relation that people thought was stable, it proceeded to change. When we plot the data for the 1970s and very early 1980s, it appears thatthe Phillips Curve had shifted to the right. This means that the trade-off worsened in this period. The data showed combinations that hadmore unemployment and also more inflation than had existed previously. Then, when one plots the data for the 1980s and 1990s, it appears that the Phillips Curve had shifted back to the left. This means that the trade-off improved in this period. There wereboth lower rates of inflation and also lower rates of unemploymentthan existed in the 1970s. By 1999, the inflation rate (using the CPI) was 2.2% and the unemployment rate was 4.2%. This combination was similar to combinations that existed in the 1960s and represented both lower rates of unemployment and lower rates of inflation than existed in the 1970s and 1980s. The idea that there is a menu of policy choices has ceased to exist.

Inflation Rate

1960s 1980s 1970s

0 1990s Unemployment Rate

So we now have three facts that we need to explain. First, why is there is Phillips Curve? That is, why is there a trade-off between inflation and unemployment? Second, why did the Phillips Curve shift to the right in the 1970s? And third, why did the Phillips Curve shift back to the left in the 1980s and 1990s?

Test Your Understanding

According to the Phillips Curve, there is an inverse relationship between inflation rates and unemployment rates. Go back to the Bureau of Labor Statistics site that you used before: (also shown as Unemployment Rate and Consumer Price Index on my web site) In a graph, plot the inflation rate and the unemployment rate for each year from 1961 to 1999.

  1. Was there an inverse relationship between inflation rates and unemployment rates between 1961 and 1969?
  2. Did the Phillips curve shift to the right in the 1970s? (This would mean that the combinations were worse than in the 1960s --- more inflation together with more unemployment)
  3. Did the Phillips curve shift to the left in the 1980s and 1990s? (This would mean that the combinations were better than in the 1970s --- less inflation together with less unemployment)

In a different framework, we encountered this trade-off previously in Chapter 9. Previously, on the horizontal axis, we plotted Real GDP. Real GDP and Unemployment are related. If unemployment is rising, Real GDP must be falling. And if unemployment is falling, Real GDP must be rising. They are inversely related. So instead of sloping down to the right, our curve sloped up to the right. We called it Aggregate Supply. (Ignore for now the fact that there is a difference between the inflation rate and the GDP Deflator on the vertical axis. This difference will not be significant for our purposes here.)

GDP Deflator

Aggregate Supply

0 Real GDP

We encountered the trade-off when we shifted aggregate demand. When aggregate demand shifted to the right, we saw that Real GDP rose and therefore unemployment fell. But the inflation rate also rose.

GDP Deflator

Aggregate Supply

P2 E2

E1

P1

Aggregate Demand2

Aggregate Demand1

0 Q1 Q2 Real GDP

And when Aggregate Demand shifted to the left, Real GDP fell (recession) and therefore unemployment rose. But prices fell (deflation).

GDP Deflator

Aggregate Supply

P1 E1

E2

P2

Aggregate Demand1

Aggregate Demand2

0 Q2 Q1 Real GDP

Therefore, in his studies, Phillips must have picked up the effects of changes in Aggregate Demand.

So again, we will have three questions to answer. We can state the questions in both frameworks. First, why is there a Phillips Curve? That is, why is there a trade-off between unemployment and inflation? We can also ask why there is an Aggregate Supply. That is, why is there a trade-off between Real GDP (production) and prices (the GDP Deflator)? Second, why did the Phillips Curve shift to the right in the 1970s? We can also ask why the Aggregate Supply shifted to the left in the 1970s. (Remember that the unemployment rate and the Real GDP are inversely related.) And third, why did the Phillips Curve shift back to the left in the 1980s and 1990s? We can also ask why the Aggregate Supply shifted back to the right in the 1980s and 1990s. In the rest of this chapter and in Chapter 24, we will consider the answer of the monetarist economists to these questions.

2. The Job Search Model

As we have said above, the monetarist view was derived from the classical view. We considered the assertion about velocity in the last chapter. Now it is time to consider the classical view’s assertion about Real GDP. Remember Say’s Law. In that view, it was asserted that Real GDP would always be equal to Potential Real GDP. There would be no recessionary gaps, except temporarily. If a recessionary gap existed, three forces would go into effect to eliminate it: prices, wages, and real interest rates would all decrease. This means that, except temporarily, cyclical unemployment would not exist. All unemployment was of the frictional, seasonal, or structural types.

The monetarist viewpoint also begins there with the assertion that recessionary gaps and cyclical unemployment will not exist, except temporarily. All unemployment is of the frictional, seasonal, or structural type. However, their explanation was more involved. In their view, the problem of unemployment derives from imperfections in the job search process. So let us begin a description of this part of the Monetarist view by examination the process of job search. Imagine you are talking to many other students and you learn that all of them are working and that all of them are earning much more than you are. So now you know that there are jobs available that are better than yours. You want to get a better job. For most people, this means that you must quit your job. Searching for a job is a major activity. You will need more time than you would have if you kept your old job. So you decide to devote your time to job searching. You will be unemployed for a while. But then you hope to find a higher paying job. You expect the increase in your income will more than offset the time you lost from work.

You encounter two problems when you enter into a job search. First, you have no idea what wage you can find. What are you worth? You don’t know. So a reasonable strategy is to aim high. You may aim too high. If you do, you will learn this because no one will offer you a job. If this happens, you can always lower your goal and accept less. But this strategy is better than one in which you take a job and then wonder if you could have found a better one if only you had continued looking. The lowest wage you are willing to accept is called your reservation wage. Over time, this reservation wage may decline for two reasons. One is that you learn that you are aiming too high (no one offers you a job). The other is that with no current job, you start to run out of funds.You might decide that you have to have a job within six weeks. If you wait longer than that, you will not have enough money to pay your rent, causing you to risk being evicted. A time chart of your reservation wage might look as follows:

$

Reservation Wage

Time

The second problem you have is finding the jobs that are available. Approximately 80% of jobs that are available are never advertised. Your best chance to find a job involves family or friends. If these are of no help, then you go door to door. You keep going back to each company. Eventually, people help you; they tell you where a job like the one you are looking for might be found. Over time, the offers become better

$ Wage Offers

Time

Over time, you become willing to take lower and lower wages (from your original high goal). Over time, you find jobs with higher and higher wages. Eventually, someone offers you a job that you are willing to accept. Let us call this time t. At that time, you are no longer unemployed.

$

Wage Offers

Reservation Wage

t Time

Take the total number of people who go through this job search process in a year. Multiply by the proportion of the year, on average, that people are unemployed and searching for a job (called the average duration of unemployment). The result tells you the annual number of unemployed people. So for example, if 24 million people go through this job search process in a given year and, on average, each is unemployed for three months (1/4 of a year), then this is the same as 6 million people (1/4 of 24 million) being unemployed for the entire year. Take this number and divide by the labor force to arrive at an unemployment rate. So, if the labor force is 150 million, the unemployment rate is 4% (6 million divided by 150 million). Monetarist economists called this unemployment rate the natural rate of unemployment. It is what we earlier called “full employment”. Everyone who is unemployed is searching for a better job. There is no cyclical unemployment (that is, there are enough jobs).

Test Your Understanding

In November 2000, the unemployment rate in America was 4%. Therefore, we think that the actual unemployment was equal to the natural rate of unemployment. In this month, the average duration of unemployment was 12.4 weeks. The total labor force was equal to 140.9 million people. Assume that these numbers existed for the entire year. How many people went through the process of searching for a job in 2000?

The existence of structural unemployment does not change this characterization. Structural unemployment means that people are unemployed because of a mismatch between their characteristics and those of the vacant jobs. They have insufficient skills. Or they are over-qualified. Or they are in the wrong location. Structurally unemployed people will simply take a longer time to find a new job than will frictionally unemployed people. If there is a greater amount of structural unemployment, the average duration of unemployment will rise. Therefore, the natural rate of unemployment will be higher.

Test Your Understanding

The natural rate of unemployment is estimated to be about 4% today. In the 1980s, it was estimated to be about 6%. By any estimation, it has fallen. Each of the following has been given as explanations for the decline. Explain why each of the following might have contributed to the decline in the natural rate of unemployment:

1. the rise in the use of temporary employment agencies

2. the decline in the number of people age 16 to 22

3. the fact that married women are more experienced workers now than they were in the 1980s

We will be using this description of the job search process to explain recent economic events. But before we do, there is one more aspect of it that we need to consider here. What determines one’s reservation wage – the lowest wage offer that one will accept? Many answers to this question are specific to an individual --- one’s education, experience, location of residence, size of family, and so forth. But one answer to this question seems to be general for all people. That answer is one’s expectations of inflation. People are interested in the real wage they receive. If they believe that prices will be rising soon, they will desire higher wages now. So the more inflation people expect, the higher is the reservation wage and vice versa. If I am your employer and I offer you a raise of 6% today, you would probably be delighted. But if I offered you the same raise in 1981, following a year in which prices rose 13.5%, you would have considered my offer an insult.

This brings us to the question: just how do we form expectations of inflation? There are two major types of expectations of future inflation. The type we will focus on in the next chapter is called adaptive expectations. With adaptive expectations, people expect the future to be similar to the present and recent past. As of this time, inflation rates are low. Inflation rates have been low for several years. With adaptive expectations, people would then assume that the inflation rate will also be low next year. We will not come to expect higher rates of inflation until after they actually happen. The other type of expectations is called rational expectations. With rational expectations, people think about the future. They understand the behavior of the economy and therefore they understand what causes inflation. So, for example, if people saw that the Federal Reserve had increased the money supply, they would come to believe that inflation rates in the future will be higher. They would therefore raise their reservation wages today, even though inflation rates have not yet risen.