Lewis' Dual Economy Model

Sources:

W.A. Lewis (1954) “Econonomic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labour” Manchester School (see especially his summary points pp. 448-49)

Wikipedia on Dual Sector model: is quite good on the basics

D. Gollin (2014) “The Lewis Model:a 60 year Retrospective” Journal of

Economic Perspectives, v. 28, 71-88.

Paul Krugman “Hitting China’s Wall” NY Times July 18, 2013 (Chinese development and its 2013 situation viewed through Lewis’ model)

- Dualism:

- View that LDC economies have two quite different sectors:

- ‘Traditional’ and ‘Modern’

- Sectors are distinguished by:

- economic organization and institutions

e.g, importance of market exchange.

Traditional: subsistence sector;

Modern: capitalist, market-driven.

- state of technology

- role of capital:

- traditional: little capital lots of labour;

- modern: more capital per worker, returns to investment

relatively high.

- Usually discussed as if:

Traditional = agriculture = rural

Modern = industry = urban

- This need not be:

- modern agriculture possible (cash crop production)

- smallretail vendors, personal service (servants) in urban

areas: also traditional?

- Lewis model: economic development involves a transformation of the

economy from one dominated by the traditional sector to one

dominated by the modern sector.

- this is what is uniquely important about it.

- like a special case of the resource allocation model.

- mobilelabour between sectors;

- add a story about capital accumulation in the Modern sector;

- this gives the Lewis model.

- Lewis model and our earlier models?

- Traditional sector: is in a world much like the Malthusian model.

- population growth has kept income (wages) at subsistence levels.

- labour is in surplus: like the Harrod-Domar model

- Capital accumulation drives growth: like Harrod-Domar and Solow models.

Lewis model

- Created in the 1950s.

- A key model of development economics.

- Intended to fit the situation of a poor country with ‘overpopulation’.

- Focus on the transformation of the economy as it develops.

- Hybrid of the microeconomic model of resource allocation and a Classical/Malthusian

model.

- Classical aspects:

- labour supply is quite elastic: ‘unlimited’ at subsistence levels in the traditional sector.

- this keeps wages low and speeds the transformation.

- savings assumptions: capitalists save.

- capital accumulation is the key to growth.

(Inspiration? Poor countries in 19th century Europe )

- It is a model of the changing allocation of labour between traditional and

modern sectors.

Modern sector

- Two factors of production: capital and labour.

- Diminishing returns: given the amount of capital the value of marginal product curve for labour(VMP) will be downward sloping.

- Employers (capitalists)

- Assume that they are "wage takers" (competitive labour market)

(modern sector wage = WM)

- To maximize profits hire more labour as long as VMP>WM, i.e. hire labour up

to the point where:

WM = VMPM(LBest in the diagram)

- Represent the entire sector by an aggregate VMPM curve (summed across employers)

- Area under the VMP curve from 0 to LBest is the total value of output

produced.

- Total wages paid: WM LBest

- Area under the VMP curve minus WM LBest is the capitalists' (employers')

income.

- Capitalists are assumed to have very high savings rates.

- Most of their income goes into creation of more physical capital.

- Savings finances investment in the modern sector.

e.g., reinvestment of profits in own firm.

- Classical assumption, e.g., Marx: capitalists have a "drive to accumulate".

- As more capital is created in the sector the VMPM curve shifts up.

- Why?each worker has more capital to work with

labour is more productive

VMP rises.

Traditional Sector

- Say it is agriculture: Labour and land is used to produce output.

- Key assumptions?

- Productivity of labour in the sector is very low (initially).

- extreme diminishing returns: abundant labour, relatively little land.

(VMP very low)

- removing labour from the sector will have little effect on output in

the sector.

i.e., labour is surplus (like in Harrod-Domar!)

- very flat, very low VMPT curve when labour force is high.

- VMPT rises little or not at all initially as labour is withdrawn from the

sector.

- How did the sector get into such a state? Some kind of Malthusian

population growth story has resulted in ‘overpopulation’.

Labour market organization in the traditional sector:

- Two possibilities:

(1) Competitive market for agricultural labourers:

- Landowners hire agricultural workers.

- Competitive market (like modern sector):

WT =VMPT

- Labour income in the sector: WTL

- Remaining income goes to landlords.

- Landlords assumed to have low saving rates (say 0):

- spend their incomes on luxuries, servants, ceremony, etc.

(2) Alternative model of traditional sector labour market:

- Communal, (extended) family model.

- All family, clan etc. members can work in the sector.

- All are guaranteed some traditional level of subsistence.

- not necessarily paid VMPT

- sharing occurs to ensure at least subsistence.

- Extreme version: complete sharing

thenWT = VAPT

VAPT = Value average product of labour

i.e. Value of output/(No. of workers)

WT = worker-farmer’s traditional sector income.

- When labour is abundant:

VAP curve is flat at a low value (subsistence)

- Saving?

- All income goes to worker-farmers but VAP is at subsistence so

virtuallynosaving.

Transformation of the Economy

- Labour is assumed to be mobile between the two sectors.

- Labour migrates to the sector which gives the highest living standard.

- Usually assumed that there is a persistent wage gap between the two sectors.

- The modern sector pays a wage premium: D

- based upon empirical observation: Modern sector seems to pay more.

- this is may be an equilibrium or compensating differential: e.g.,

- compensation for living cost differences

- non-monetary costs of working in the modern sector.

- premium needed to cover mobility costs.

Lewis extra Modern sector pay compensates for:

“psychological cost of transferring from the easy going way of life of the subsistence

sector to the more regimented and urbanised environment of the capitalist sector.”

- Short-run equilibrium:

- Labour migrates between the two sectors until:

WT + D = WM

- The wage gap (WM-WT) is equal to the differential needed to attract workers

into modern sector.

(see for example pt. 0 in the following diagram when VMP0M is the VMP

curve in the Modern sector and VMPT is the VMP curve in the Traditional sector)

- Growth and movement to a new short-run equilibrium:

- Capitalists save and reinvest their income in the modern sector.

- Capital stock in modern sector now grows.

- So: VMPM curve shifts up to (VMP0M to VMP1M)

WM rises temporarily (to WMtemp given labour allocation is L0)

WT + D < WM

Migration from traditional to modern sector

WM falls as migration occurs (economy moving from pt. 1 toward

pt. 2)

Migration stops once: WT + D = WM(at pt. 2: new allocation of labour is at L1)

- At the end of this stage:

- morelabour in the modern sector

- wages are unchanged (note role of flat VMPT or VAPT)

- capitalists' incomes have risen.

- savings rate has risen since capitalists share of income is rising.

- More saving and reinvestment occurs the process repeats itself.

- VMPM for modern sector continues to shift up

- Modern sector grows, traditional sector shrinks

- But traditional sector output may not fall much: low productivity.

- Output of the two sectors combined is rising:

- difference of the VMPs on each unit of L transferred.

- Eventually the "turning point" is reached.

- Point where VMPT or VAPT starts to rise significantly.

i.e., surplus labourin the Traditional sector is exhausted.

- Further shifts in VMPM will cause a rise in wages in each sector.

- temporary boom in modern sector wages is not entirely reversed.

- rising productivity in traditional sector means the traditional sector

start to pay more: labour no longer in surplus!

- This will slow and perhaps stop the shift of labour.

Rising wages  less income for capitalists  less extra saving

- Also as capital grows in the modern sector more savings will go to

replacing worn out capital.

- Capital stock may eventually stabilize.

- It is possible that the traditional sector will be completely absorbed.

(e.g. if reach VMP5M in diagram)

Summary of the model's predictions

- Transformation of the economy will occur.

- traditional/agriculture shrinks.- modern industry grows.

- Transformation is driven by growing incomes of capitalists and capital

accumulation in the modern sector.

- Savings rates will rise during the development process.

(notice reliance on capitalists getting much of the extra income)

- Wages will not rise during the transformation:

reflects surplus traditional sector labour

- early Industrial Revolution an example.

- Income inequality will rise during the development process.

- After the turning point, rising wages will slow and possibly stop the

transformation.

- End result: transformation slows and ends.

- Growth from reallocation ends.

- No longer a surplus labour economy. Rising wages.

- Krugman “Hitting China’s Wall”

- Is China at or approaching this point?

- Fast growth since early-1980s partly reflects transformation.

- moving resources from low-productivity sectors to higher

productivity sectors.

Complications and Criticisms

- Transformation from traditional to modern is key to development.

- Is it automatic?

- Can government or aid spur this transformation?

- Some have transformed some have not: why?

- Acemoglu and Johnson Why Nations Fail Ch.9

- Why a dual economy?

(discussion of South Africa as a created dual economy;

plantation economies; Latin America as well?)

- Does it reflect political and economic institutions?

- Is transformation impossible without different institutions?

- Model: Capitalists save their income domestically.

- demonstration effects: will they instead use their incomes to import

luxuries from MDCs?

- capital flight: will they send savings abroad?

where are the highest and safest returns?

- Terms of trade between sectors:

- Model above does not discuss what happens to prices of traditional and

modern sector output.

- These prices also determine: VMPM and VMPT

- A sharp rise in price of traditional output vs. modern sector output could

slow or halt the transformation.

- low productivity in agriculture: early in the process supply of

traditional output changes little so price may be stable.

- modern sector output:

- could price fall as sector expands?

- less likely if the output is exported.

(does the model best fit countries who are exporting modern sector output? Otherwise who buys the output?)

- Modern "enclave" as an equilibrium outcome

- A case of stalled transformation.

- Why might it stall?

- Terms of trade between sectors.

- Modern sector may be resource based:

- limited by resource availability.

- Wages early-on rise for reasons outside the model: policy, unions?

- Traditional sector is passive in this model.

- This sector plays a passive role: provides a supply of labour to the modern

sector.

- extralabour helps create capitalist's income, generates savings, this

drives development.

- Policies:Anti-traditional sector bias

e.g., encourage industry (modern)

neglect agriculture (traditional)

- taxation or marketing boards can be used to extract surplus from

traditional sector.

- too much extraction: famine, weak incentives to produce.

(Soviet Union, China, African examples in Acemoglu & Johnson)

- Traditional sector: viewed as custom-tradition bound, decision-making little

affected by incentives.

- evidence suggests the contrary.

- Idea that saving and accumulation can from the rural sector.

- could also fuel investment.

- A healthy agricultural sector can be important to development

- urban wages rise with the price of foodstuffs

- China since 1978: agricultural reforms important early in the process.

- village levelenterprises.

J. Studwell(2013) How Asia Works : on East Asian success stories claims

that agricultural reform was important in all successful cases.

- Surplus labour assumption

- Early version of the model claimed VMP=0 in the traditional sector:

this appears to be wrong.

- how flat is the VMP curve in the traditional sector

- wages often not as stable as the model predicts.

- Empirical support for agriculture having low productivity vs. industry receives

much support.

1