Submission for Annual ASSA-AREUEA Conference 2006

Developer’s Reputation and Market Structure: Why is real estate market an oligopoly?

Dong, Zhi*1, Sing, Tien Foo*2 and Shilling, James D.*3

Date: March 24, 2005

Abstract

Eaton and Schmitt [9] develop a theory of market structure for manufacturing firms,
which is developed using Hotelling model as kernel, and the theory suggests that flexibility in manufacturing technology promotes concentration through preemption, mergers and cartels. They also examine how flexible manufacturing technology can be utilized by first moversin the industry to preempt new entrants under two conditions: perfectly price inelastic demand and responsive demand.

Real estate market is inherently local in nature. Product is highly segmented and differentiated at the submarket level. The development technology for real estate product is, however, less sophisticated and yet labor intensive. It, therefore, does not fit into the specification of flexibility technologyin the early model by Eaton and Schmitt [9]. Why is real estate market then dominated by few developers?What are the factors that promote concentration in the real estate market? Does the concentration of market structure through monopoly pre-emption lead to welfare-optimal equilibrium in real estate market? There is, as far as we know, no literature in real estate that specifically examines the questions of market structure, and the welfare effects of the market concentration in the real estate market.

Combining the literature on market structure for manufacturing firms (Baumol [3], Baumol et al. [4], Eaton and Lemche [8], Eaton and Schmitt [9], Mazzeo [24]), reputation and information (Kreps and Wilson [19], Shapiro [30], Shapiro [31], Allen [1], Fudenberg and Kreps [12], Tadelis [34], Hörner [15]), and predatory pricing(Spence [33], Rosenthal [27], Milgrom and Roberts [26]), this paper developsa model that links developer’s reputation to the evolution of a concentrated market structure in real estate market, taking into account ofvarious constraints in development technology and product.

Understanding the formation and implication of real estate market structure will also help to identify sub-game optimal strategies for developers in the process of market share and reputation building over the long run.

Reputation is an endogenous variable in a repeated game framework. It is a valuable asset to developers, and good reputation will take time to cultivate(Tadelis [34], and Hörner [15]. In our proposed framework with two developers and one market place with two real estate sectors, one of the developers has already established its foothold in one sector of the market, whereas the second developer is new entrant to the market. For the incumbent developer, he has an option of either expanding the product type to meet demand of other users in the market or focusing on the current product segment that he is already involved in. The sunk costs for both strategies include land costs. The product expansion/diversification strategy, however, incurs additional fixed cost, which is consistent with the flexible technology assumption in Eaton and Schmitt [9]. To the new entrant, he will have to incur a fixed product development cost, if he plans to develop one of the real estate types in the new market. Given that new supply of lands is a sequential process, the new entrant has to compete by bidding for new land parcel at a cost, which is exogenous in the model. The incumbent developer may adopt a monopoly pre-emption strategy that will drive out the new entrant, or hemay choose to continue to expand the market share in his preferred market sector. In the second period, both developers may explore “merger” or “cartel” options in the optimal sub-game strategiesthat will lead to concentration in the market, or they may continue to pursue non-cooperative strategies. The dynamic market ownership structures under various sub-game scenarios are analyzed and the results are compared with those found by Eaton and Schmitt’s [9] models in manufacturing industry.

In Eaton and Schmitt’s [9] model, entry is independent on product ownership structure given that all firms can manufacture flexibly. In our model, when reputation building is taken into consideration, it may be in the long run benefits of incumbent developers to exert some forms of deterrence to new entrant. In merger case, reputation may have negative profit externality on relative developers, a result which contrasts the earlier findings of Eaton and Schmitt [9], which proposes that merger has no influence on other relative firms. In our proposed model that is not dependent on flexible technology, reputation building and its associated costs appear to be important factors in promoting or limiting the concentration of real estate market. Differences in reputation costs between the incumbent developer and the new entrant, coupled with various sub-game optimal strategies adopted by them, may provide some explanation on the formation of real estate market structure. The model can also be extended to cover multiple players with different product space, {(x, q) = [(x1, q1), (x2, q2), …. ,(xm, qm)]} where xi denotes the productitype in the attribute space, qi denotes the quantity of product xi, and m denotes the maximum product type in the market space, and the cooperative strategies in the reputation building and entry deterrence processes can also be evaluated.

Key words(JEL Classification):Market Structure (L13),Economics of Information (L15), Reputation.

*1 Department of Real Estate, NationalUniversity of Singapore ()

*2Department of Real Estate, NationalUniversity of Singapore ()

*3School of Business, University of Wisconsin – Madison ()

References

1.F. Allen, Reputation and product quality, The RAND Journal of Economics, 15, 311-327 (1984).

2.L. M. Ausubel and R. J. Deneckere, Reputation in Bargaining and durable goods monopoly, Econometrica, 57, 511-531 (1989).

3.W. J. Baumol, Contestable markets: an uprising in the theory of industry structure, The American Economic Review, 72, 1-15 (1982).

4.W. J. Baumol, J. C. Panzar and R. D. Willig, Contestable markets: an uprising in the theory of industry structure: reply, The American Economic Review, 73, 491-496 (1983).

5.G. E. Bolton and A. Ockenfels, ERC: A theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition, The American Economic Review, 90, 166-193 (2000).

6.J. A. Brander and J. Eaton, Product line rivalry, The American Economic Review, 74, 323-334 (1984).

7.J. I. Bulow, Durable goods monopolists, Journal of Political Economy, 90, 314-332 (1982).

8.B. C. Eaton and S. Q. Lemche, The geometry of supply, demand, and competitive market structure with economies of scope, The American Economic Review, 81, 901-911 (1991).

9.B. C. Eaton and N. Schmitt, Flexible manufacturing and market structure, The American Economic Review, 84, 875-888 (1994).

10.E. F. Fama and A. B. Laffer, The number of firms and competition, American EconomicReview, 62, 670-674 (1972).

11.E. F. Fama and A. B. Laffer, The number of firms and competition: reply, American Economic Review, 64, 806 (1974).

12.D. Fudenberg and D. M. Kreps, Reputation in the simultaneous play of multiple opponents, The Review of Economic Studies, 54, 541-568 (1987).

13.D. Fudenberg and J. Tirole, A theory of exit in duopoly, Econometrica, 54, 943-960 (1986).

14.D. Gale and R. W. Rosenthal, Price and quality cycles for experience goods, The RAND Journal of Economics, 25, 590-607 (1994).

15.J. Hörner, Reputation and competition, The American Economic Review, 92, 644-663 (2002).

16.S. Klepper, Entry, exit, growth, and innovation over the product life cycle, The American Economic Review, 86, 562-583 (1996).

17.D. M. Kreps, P. Milgrom, J. Roberts and R. Wilson, Rational cooperation in the finitely repeated prisoners’ dilemma, Journal of Economic Theory, 27, 245-252 (1982).

18.D. M. Kreps and R. Wilson, Sequential equilibria, Econometrica, 50, 863-894 (1982).

19.D. M. Kreps and R. Wilson, Reputation and imperfect information, Journal of Economic Theory, 27, 253-279 (1982).

20.W. J. Lane, Product differentiation in a market with endogenous sequential entry, Bell Journal of Economics, 11, 237-260 (1980).

21.P. J. Lederer and A. P. Hurter, Competition of firms: discriminatory pricing and location, Econometrica, 54, 623-640 (1986).

22.E. Maskin and J. Tirole, A theory of dynamic oligopoly, I: overview and quantity competition with large fixed costs, Econometrica, 56, 549-569 (1988).

23.E. Maskin and J. Tirole, A theory of dynamic oligopoly, II: price competition, kinked demand curves, and edgeworth cycles, Econometrica, 56, 571-599 (1988).

24.M. J. Mazzeo, Product choice and oligopoly market structure, The RAND Journal ofEconomics, 33, 221-242 (2002).

25.P. Milgrom and J. Roberts, Limit pricing and entry under incomplete information: an equilibrium analysis, Econometrica, 50, 443-459 (1982).

26.P. Milgrom and J. Roberts, Predation, reputation and entry deterrence, Journal of Economic Theory, 27, 280-312 (1982).

27.R. W. Rosenthal, Games of perfect information, predatory pricing and the chain-store paradox, Journal of Economic Theory, 25, 92-100 (1981).

28.R. W. Rosenthal, A dynamic model of duopoly with customer loyalties, Journal of Economic Theory, 27, 69-76 (1982).

29.A. Shaked and J. Sutton, Relaxing price competition through product differentiation, Review of Economic Studies, 49, 3-13 (1982).

30.C. Shapiro, Consumer information, product quality, and seller reputation, Bell Journal of Economics, 13, 20-35 (1982).

31.C. Shapiro, Premiums for high quality products as returns to reputations, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98, 659-679 (1983).

32.C. T. Somerville, The industrial organization of housing supply: market activity, land supply and the size of homebuilder firms, 27, 669-694 (1999).

33.A. M. Spence, Entry, capacity, investment and oligopolistic pricing, Bell Journal ofEconomics, 8, 534-544 (1979).

34.S. Tadelis, What’s in a name? Reputation as a tradeable asset, The American Economic Review, 89, 548-563 (1999).

1