Torts Outline – Professor Turley

I. Schools of Thought

A.  Formalism

1. Code system, consisting of canons, case-made, judge-made rules

2. Rules are “outcome determinative”; goal- prevent bias/ subjectivity of judges

3. Fierce notion of judicial neutrality/deference; court should not engage in determining what law should be rather than what it is; leave lawmaking to legislative branch

B.  Legal Realism- replaced Formalism in the Torts Revolution

1. Rejection of formalism; acceptance of the indeterminacy of the law

2. Karl Llewellyn found judges selected canons and pre-determined outcome (hidden bias); false neutrality

a. Began policy goal of creating a stable rule; consider broader implications

b. consider what reasonable person would have done and the goal of achievement

C.  Normative

1. Goal- determine what is “norm of society”, what is morally right/wrong in society, usually decided by jury

D.  Hobbes- Leviathan guarantees recourse/ remedy; corrective justice- law must make wrongs right vs. efficiency of CLS (producing most efficient manner of achieving wealth maximization rather than righting of wrongs)

E.  Lockean

1. Labor Theory: In beginning, all was held in common. Then evolved into private property (mixing of sweat/labor = conversion of common property into private property)

2. Gvmt does not create priv. property- God created private property; gvmt may not redistribute wealth

3. Locke’s Proviso: One must leave “as good and enough for others” (used by Rawls to justify redistribution if extreme concentration of wealth occurs b/c it is defeating God’s plan of allowing man to produce through enterprise)

F.  Utilitarianism

1. gvmt must protect individuals, not just market

2. Bentham- goal of gvmt- achieve the greatest good for greatest number; invest in social action à tremendous productivity (industrial revolution); gvmt = engineer of society

G.  Feminism

1. Katherine MacKinnon- law written by middle-aged white men- inherent patriarchal bias

2. Jurispathic v. jurisgenerative

a. Jurispathic- basis of law is combative, male model; lawyer is knight; zero sum game- only one person wins/ gains

b. Better à Jurisgenerative- judges evaluate merit on both sides and shape an equitable decision

3. Bender- should have duty to perform low-cost rescues; Posner agrees, but from an efficiency standpoint

H.  Critical Legal Studies

1. Goal- judges should actively work to break down class barriers; help marginalized

2. Sometimes favored judicial activism, courts should be more socially active

3. Duncan Kennedy- peeled onion of Blackstone’s Commentaries

a. Favored de-construction of ‘legal terms’

b. Wealth re-distribution is important (Rawls)

I.  CLS counted by Judicial Restraint

1. Goal- deference to the legislature; judges are not elected and are counter-majoritarian

2. Madisonian System:

a. Tri-part gvmt provides checks balances

b. Factions à political pressure à majority rule (elimination of factions)

c. If left to judges- no faction pressure relief, too much control given to individual

3. Hart and Sachs- the system works best when courts leave it to legislature to fill gaps/ ambiguous legislation; Courts must stay in line w/the Madisonian system

J.  But see- Public Choice Movement

a. Hart and Sachs view is wrong; gvmt often favors minority opinions rather than majority principles; deals/gaps = Congress making decisions to detriment of public

b. Mancur Olson

i. disagrees with Madison’s view- collective action: small groups are actually more powerful than big groups b/c small groups have concentrated interest

ii. vs. majority groups, that have dispersed interests and more free riders

c. Easterbrook

i. Dealism- gaps in legislation are bought and sold like a market

ii. Court must apply laws exactly as written; do NOT gap fill: limited judicial role

d. Jonathan Macey- agreed w/public choice criticism, but not the result

i. DO gap fill; take Congress at its word and enforce the “public-regarding purpose” of legislation; Congress can fix it if wrong

ii. Madisonian democracy works best when open and deliberative process; this is achieved by filling gaps to public regarding purpose, forcing Congress to amend out in open to continue deal-making

K.  Hegel

1. Personality theory of property- the subjective value of an object to an individual is not recognized by the law- disconnect

2. the only way to understand property is to understand its relationship to the person

L.  Law and Economics School

1. Goal- efficiency, not morality

2. Posner

a. morality is bad basis for law b/c of subjectivity; it’s indeterminate; focus on economic efficiency instead, which is more tangible and will improve the living conditions

b. Negligence is the most effective system; strict liability forces cost-internalization, leaving it to the market to dispose of inefficient activities

3. 2 most common definitions of EFFICIENCY:

a. Pareto Efficiency

i. Goal- get a pareto superior result- produces at least one winner and doesn’t make anyone worse off- making things more efficient

ii. Pareto optimality- point of optimal efficiency; point before first loser is produced

b. Kador-Hicks Efficiency

i. Goal- wealth maximization; producing losers doesn’t matter as long as there is a net gain; no need to compensate losers

4. Externalities

a. Rational actors try to externalize their cost to others (i.e. externalizing pollution)

b. Hardin’s Tragedy of the commons- wealth maximizing farmers will continue to add cows to shared land w/finite amt. of grass even if doing so will cause the land to stop producing food; result- everyone starves

i. Solution? Introduce private property à creates incentive to keep resource healthy

5. Pigou

a. only legislate when the market fails by allowing something contrary to the long-term needs of society

b. Examples- stimulus package; force a discriminatory firm off market w/legislation

6. Coase Theorum

a. Coase I- in a perfect market, the market determines the outcome of conflicts btw two uses – more valuable resource will ultimately prevail (farmer/ rancher ex.)

i. redistribution/regulation not necessary- market will handle it

b. Coase II- there is no perfect market; must include transactional costs (cost of reaching an accord btw parties), which can cause the outcome to flip- less valuable activity can continue b/c of the high transaction cost of stopping the activity; fewer people affected = higher transactional costs (Turleyworks ex.)

II. Intentional Harm

A.  Background

1. Intent

a. Rest. § 1: Conduct is intentional if the actor:

i. desires the result/consequence (“purpose” intent); OR

ii. knows or believes the result is substantially certain to occur (“knowledge” intent)

·  little boy knew old lady would be hurt when he pulled chair out in Garret v. Daly

·  Children may be held liable of intent

b. intent inferred from conduct, not motive

c. Transferred intent- A hits C when intending to hit B; C claims transferred intent; 1st you must establish original intent

2. Traditional defense- consent

3. Basic Types

a. Physical Harm: Trespass to person, land, and chattels

i. Tresspass to person

·  Vosburg v. Putney

o  Rule Violation- Putney kicks Π in shin, lost use of leg

o  held responsible, even for unforeseen damages

o  Rule- For intent, it is sufficient to show rule violation, the natural cause of which is injury

ii. Trespass to Land- intent to enter someone else’s land, even if by reasonably mistake (i.e. because unaware it’s someone else’s property)

iii. Trespass to Chattels- intentional dispossession of a thing; loss in valuable int’st

·  trespass to chattel (stolen but returnable) vs. conversion (destroyed, unreturnable)

·  Rst. § 218, 19: Liable for direct/ indirect phys. contact causing impairment: of condition, quality, value.

o  Intangible property: Intel v. Hamidi- trespass to chattels claim fails- emails did not damage the computer system

b. Physical Harm: Conversion

i. Rst. § 222- intentional exercise of control over chattel, which seriously interferes w/Π’s right to control

ii. Moore v. Regents of Univ. Cal.- organ removed from body, used for science ($). Usually put in trash so NO conversion.

·  RULE: custom of chattel disposal effects determination of conversion

·  Possible Defenses:

o  slippery slope

o  slippery slope- if you say removal of tissue is conversion, huge # of issues

o  bright light argument- say this is not priv. property or slippery slope

o  floodgates- if tissue is priv. property, thousands of patients whose tissue was used in research

c. Physical Harm: DEFENSES to Intentional Torts

i. Consensual Defenses- consent vitiates intent

·  Rst. § 892: consent when one is willing for conduct to occur

o  Need- Π’s subjective state of mind consent

o  Don’t Need- communication to Δ

o  Apparent consent- Π’s words or conduct is enough (i.e. implied consent in the O’Brien case- stick out arm, stand in line, receive unwanted vaccination)

o  Mohr v. Williams- Dr. diagnoses left ear, while Π sedated, operates on other ear à civil assault and battery

§  Rule: Need consent

§  Issue: Patient’s awareness of consent, and to what

·  Emergency Rule- Dr.s are not required to get consent if a person is seriously injured (i.e. unconscious or severe pain) and time is of the essence

·  Proper, informed consent is required

o  Canterbury v. Spence- Π has back surgery, left unattended, not instruct to stay still, falls off bed

§  Issue: Duty to disclose risks in acquisition of consent?

§  Rule: “Informed consent” is required

·  Rule: You can’t consent to something illegal

o  Hudson v. Craft- Π, minor, goes to carnival, injured in boxing match

§  Issue: Did consent to illegal activity negate Δ’s responsibility?

§  Rule: If you are part of a protected class (i.e. minor), court may ignore consent.

·  Rule: Public policy can require consent- duty to disclose.

o  I.e. If you have an STD, you have a duty to disclose (or be held liable). If you do disclose, even if transmission occurs, no liability.

ii. Insanity: Insane/estate usually held liable

·  McGuire v. Almy- Π, nurse caretaker, insane Δ hit nurse on head w/table leg

o  Rule: Insane held liable for their intentional torts.

o  Court uses cheapest cost avoider to determine family is CCA. Turley- nurse/hospital CCA b/c they can get insurance, and nurse knows the danger.

iii. Self-Defense

·  RST § 63: Rule: May only use reasonable force against imminent harm.

·  Rule: May only use commensurate force.

o  May not escalate the encounter by increasing the violence.

·  Rule: You do not have to retreat.

o  But may not retaliate once danger is passed. Battered women syndrome not accepted- viewed as retaliation.

·  Rule: Mistaken self-defense must be reasonable.

o  Courvoisier v. Raymond- Δ fending off intruders, confuses cop w/intruder and shoots

§  Rule: Reasonable, mistaken belief of self defense is reasonable.

·  3rd party privilege to defend others under same conditions and by same means as one may defend self.

iv. Defense of Property

·  RST § 77: Rule: May use reasonable force; MAY NOT use force calculated to cause serious bodily injury or death in defense of property. Human life more sacred than property. May use molitor manus- laying gentle hands.

·  Curtilage- the area around a home that is protected

·  Rule: May NOT have lethal devices that cannot distinguish btw friend/ foe.

o  Bird v. Holbrook- walled garden w/spring gun kills kid

o  Rule: Human life worth more than property; lethal traps illegal.

·  Rule: Notice is necessary to prevent liability for use of non-lethal devices that can cause injury that are not patent (i.e. electric fence, hidden barbed wire). Patent (visible) barbed-wire is a warning itself.

·  Controversial: Castle Doctrine/ Make My Day- whenever someone intrudes your domicile, you may use the full range of self-protection (i.e. lethal force ok)

v. Recapture of Chattels

·  RST § 100: Limited self-help privilege- reasonable force requirement, recapture must begin promptly

·  Kirby v. Foster- Π has gained rightful possession of $, Δ fights for it back

o  Rule: Reasonable force may be used ONLY when dispossession was unlawful

vi. Necessity

·  An otherwise trespass/conversion on Π allowed in preservation of life or property.

·  Ploof v. Putnam- Π, family sailing in storm, moor to Δ’s dock, dock’s owner unmoors boat

o  Rule: There is a duty to allow acts of necessity in order to preserve human life.

·  Vincent v. Lake Erie Transportation Co.- Δ re-ties failed ropes of boat to dock during storm, dock damaged by boat

o  Rule: Privilege of private necessity does not negate duty to pay for damages.

o  Turley: Reverse arg.- dock owner may be CCA (insurance, internalize costs). Ability to sue for lost opportunity costs unclear.

·  Public necessity- “champion of the common good”; if acting for public good, may destroy public property and not be held liable

o  Gvmt may always use this argument, but gvmt has waived much of its immunity

§  i.e. U.S. gvmt compensates war-time victims

o  Most states have restricted it to keep ppl from claiming it

d. Emotional/Dignitary Harm: Assault

i. RST § 21: Assault- intent to cause reasonable apprehension of imminent battery

·  Need: Intention + Act

ii. Δ must have intent to cause offensive contact or imminent apprehension (Π’s awareness of threat)

iii. Rule: Mere words are not enough to constitute assault

e. Emotional/Dignitary Harm: OFFENSIVE BATTERY

i. RST § 18: Battery: Intent to cause offensive contact + offensive contact

ii. If no intention, then only negligent, reckless act, NOT offensive battery.

f. Emotional/Dignitary Harm: False Imprisonment

i. False Imprisonment- Δ intends to confine Π w/in boundaries fixed by Δ, and Π is conscious of the confinement or harmed by it

·  Intent is all that’s necessary; mistake is not a defense.

·  False arrest = false imprisonment

·  Future threats do not equal false imprisonment

ii. Bird v. Jones- Π disallowed to continue down blocked highway

·  Rule: Effective confinement required for false imprisonment.

iii. Possible Scenarios:

·  Acts of negligence (i.e. stuck on elevator/plane) do not equal false imprisonment.

·  Confined in a room, but no restraint? Not false imprisonment

·  Confined in a room, but a high window gives escape? False imprisonment

iv. Coblyn v. Kennedy’s- old man trapped in store after suspected shoplifting

·  Rule: Short-term ‘imprisonment’ against shoplifters ok if reasonable (equivalent to citizen’s arrest). Time/place/manner is critical to reasonableness.