Monopolistic Competition

- Source: Ch. 13 Section 13.B pp. 465-469.

- Monopolistic competition: A market structure where firms in the industry

produce products that are close substitutes for one another.

- Each firm has monopoly power over its own unique variant of the product.

- Each firm competes for market share with industry rivals producing similar

products.

- Classic (Chamberlin) version assumes free entry.

- What is an industry here?

- producers of similar products, e.g., brands of soft drink, soap,

breakfast cereal, cars, etc.

- Differentiated products: how and why do they differ?

- individual consumer preferences differ over product characteristics

e.g. appearance, taste, etc.

- Firms create a variety that appeals to a certain clientele.

- advertising may make consumers view similar goods differently.

(are there other actions businesses can take to make consumers

view similar or identical goods differently?)

- fashion or fads: can collective preferences create differentiation?

Chamberlin’s Model of Monopolistic Competition:

- Key assumptions of the model:

(1) firms in an industry produce heterogeneous (differentiated)

products: each firm is a price maker for its variant of the good;

- vs. perfect competition: identical products.

- some monopoly power over own variety.

(2) firms do not behave strategically: each ignores the effects of its

actions on its competitors.

- chooses output and sets price assuming this choice has

no effect on competitors choice.

- this is easiest to defend if firms in the model are small

compared to the industry (as in perfect competition)

(3) entry of new firms is relatively costless;

- like perfect competition unlike monopoly.

(4) buyers are small (price takers).

- Endogenous variables: prices, quantities, number of firms and varieties

(long-run).

- Exogenous variables: determinants of demand and costs.

- Individual Firm’s Demand curve in Monopolistic Competition:

- downward sloping:

- high price: only those with a strong preference

for your variant of the product buy it.

- low price: those with a strong preference for your variant still

buy, but so do others who substitute your (cheap) product for otherwise preferable variants.

- this holds prices of similar products produced by other firms

constant

(demand is less elastic if prices of all similar

products change simultaneously see DD).

(Text: “DD” curve – shows how demand changes if all firms change prices simultaneously .

- DD steeper: less substitution as prices for all varieties change

simultaneously.

- Useful for thinking about how “collusion” outcome differs and for

thinking about efficiency of the outcome. )

- Demand curve is also affected by the number of monopolistic

competitors.

- more competitors:

- demand likely more elastic (more close substitutes)

- demand shifts left (smaller market share at any

given price).

- Short-run:

- Act like a monopolist: produce at output where MR = MC.

- Say that at this outcome: Price > ATC (economic profit made).

- Price is also a markup over MC (like monopoly).

- Long-run:

- Entry occurs in response to short-run profits.

- Entry here means new firms producing new varieties of the good.

- Demand for each existing firm shifts left and becomes flatter.

- output at which MR = MC shrinks.

- Entry continues until profits are eliminated.

- at this point demand for each firm has shifted left to the point

where it is tangent to the ATC curve and where MR=MC

at this output.

- if the heterogenous goods are very close substitutes: outcome

almost identical to perfect competition.

i.e., since demand curve is nearly flat.

- Flatter (more elastic) demand in long-run means price markup may

be small.

- Evaluating the monopolistically competitive outcome?

- long-run outcome: tangent to downward sloping part of the long-run

ATC curve.

- firms are “too small”: they produce less than their minimum

efficient scale (MES).

(MES: output level at which LRAC is at its minimum)

- efficiency loss: produces where MR = MC not where P=MC.

- But is there an offsetting benefit to monopolistic competition?

- consumers may value variety:

- having heterogeneous products can increase consumer

surplus;

- if so it is unclear whether having fewer, larger scale firms but

less variety makes society better off.

- What if the consumer preference for a new variant is created

by advertising?

- is there really any benefit to variety then?

- important question: welfare economics assumes

preferences are not created by

economic decisions.

- how to judge economic outcomes if preferences

are created?

(“customer loyalty” schemes e.g. frequent flier points –

do they make issuer’s profit different to some

buyers? – similar issues to advertising)

Importance of Monopolistic Competition:

- Provides a way of thinking about product diversity, why it arises and its

pros and cons.

- A version of the model can be solved for a general equilibrium (across all

markets simultaneously): unusual for non-competitive market structures.

- Dixit-Stiglitz Model: widely used in international trade, growth,

location and macroeconomic literatures.

- Can combine this structure with oligopoly models.

For example: a hybrid

- Differentiated products (like monopolistic competition (M.C.) unlike

oligopoly)

- Demand curves of firms interdependent (true in both M.C. and olig.)

- Restricted entry: like oligopoly, unlike M.C. e.g. say two firms.

- Can build a Cournot or Bertrand style model by allowing output or

pricing decisions of firm producing one variety to affect the demand curve of a firm producing another variety.

(time permitting: could do Bertrand with differentiated products – more interesting reaction functions than when products are identical e.g. see Perloff’s Coke-Pepsi example)
Locational Models as Versions of Monopolistic Competition:

- Monopolistic competitors:

- products are differentiated – imperfect substitutes.

- products differ in some way that matters to consumer.

- Usually think of this in terms of different product characteristics:

- taste of the soft-drink, style of shirt or car, etc.

- another way in which products differ between different firms is in

location of the firm providing the product.

- model in Ch. 13, pp. 469-478: identical physical product but sold at

different locations.

- In this case products differ in a readily measurable way:

- distance from the consumer ;

- dollar equivalent: transportation costs of obtaining the

product.


Hotelling’s Model of Firm Location (Ice Cream/Hot Dog Vendor Model):

- See text (Ch. 13, p. 476)

- A classic example:

- location problem given location of consumers.

- choice of location determines market share: given distribution of

customers.

- Uniform distribution of customers along a beach:

- demand fixed at 1 each, price $1 per ice cream cone.

- Customers go to the closest vendor (minimize transport costs)

- Preferred location?

- One vendor: any location on the beach.

- Two vendors:

- Consider locations ¼ and ¾ along the beach.

- Each vendor serves ½ of the beach (market area).

- Is this an equilibrium? No!

- Say one vendor is mobile:

- moves toward the other firm: expands market area.

- best location: adjacent to competitor.

- Now let both firms move: leapfrog to the center.

- Equilibrium:

- Firms adjacent in the center of the market.

- Interesting point: inefficient from view of

transport costs.

- More generally: median location result.

- assume customers are not uniformly distributed but

more concentrated at some points than other.

- firms will move to the median location: 50% of the market on

either side.

- How general is the result?

- Three vendors: no equilibrium!

(oddly with other numbers there generally is).

- Allowing for price competition and location choice: no

simple equilibrium outcome.

Hotelling’s Model and Product Differentiation

- Consumers differ by location in Hotelling’s model.

- Imagine they differ by tastes for some characteristic of a good and that

differences in taste can be represented as points along a line.

- Can get Hotelling-like clustering:

- firms decide on the type of good (point on the line) in order to

capture customers closest in taste to that type.

- tendency to produce similar goods results: just like in the location

model firms locate near each other.

- does this mean there is too little variety?

- but what if product differentiation is created by advertising? Does

that mean there is too much variety?

11